Tuesday, July 15, 2025

Today's Bee letter: Utilities

Responding to Sacramento Bee 7/17/25 p.20

Editorial writer Tom Philp wrings his hands over a Chamber of Commerce study that says solar incentives may cost 14% of a "typical ratepayer bill." Heavens to Betsy!

This is straining at a gnat while swallowing a camel. Publicly-owned SMUD is 35% cheaper than privately-owned PG&E. The savings from publicly-owned utilities beats the solar "cost" calculated by one of the most conservative organizations in the country by more than double. 

We'd save big from public ownership, and wouldn't have an incentive for executives to boost profit by skimping on maintenance. PG&E executives were concerned they would have to face negligent homicide charges for their maintenance failures like the exploding pipeline in San Bruno and the fire that burned down the ironically-named town of "Paradise."

Priorities, please.

Monday, July 14, 2025

Copaganda part II

 Alec Karakatsanis, author of the Copaganda book in a brief talk (from here)

 
 
 Here's an excerpt from the text in which the video was embedded:
 
"As I suggest in the video, our civil rights work is about many things, including getting as many people as we can out of cages. But the work we do in courts and jails across the U.S. is also about something else: it’s about ensuring that, no matter what kinds of grotesque stuff starts to become normalized in a society that imprisons Black people 6 times the rate of South Africa at the height of Apartheid and all people 5-10 times other comparable countries, there are always people prepared to say “2+2=4.” The moment people stop saying this, everything is lost.

"One reason various institutions are crumbling and the people in charge of them so unpopular is that the material reality they defend is so different from their own professed values. They claim to value the “rule of law” but only enforce some laws against some people some of the time. They claim to value “public safety” but pursue policies that make most people less safe. They claim to value liberty but jail hundreds of thousands of society’s poorest people solely because they lack access to cash. They claim to value equality but ensure a small number of people control nearly every major decision. They claim to value evidence but pursue policies that defy evidence. They claim to value health but let us all be regularly poisoned and then destroy the opportunity for most people to get quality health care. They claim to value merit but ensure that fealty to power is what gets rewarded in elite institutions. As a result, establishment politicians, university presidents, and pundits are constantly speaking gibberish instead of being real with people."



Warren Mosler Evaluates Trump's Policies

 (The graph is the unemployment rate)

Links 7/14/25 - Too good to overlook

First, there's Matt Stoller's analysis of the Trump administration's refusal to release the Jeffrey Epstein files.


Excerpt: "Over the last twenty years, a larger-than-life myth has floated around the American political scene, that of Jeff Epstein, a wealthy New York City-based sex trafficker with a murky job and deep connections to some of the most powerful men in America, England, and Israel. Continual revelations around Epstein have fueled MAGA suspicion of big media, big tech, and big government, fostering a mini-ecosystem of Donald Trump-supportive podcasters and influencers. Trump would, they posited, finally expose a Deep State conspiracy, the center of which was this man, Epstein.

Epstein with Uber-Neoliberal "Economist" Larry Summers

"Last week, however, Trump did something I thought was impossible - he managed to turn his own core supporters against him. He did so by denying that there is anything conspiratorial or hidden about Epstein’s life or the circumstances of his death. Specifically, Trump said there were no government files worth releasing around Epstein, and the idea of such files was a Democratic party plot. I looked at the replies to his post on Truth Social, as such posts are always full of supporters offering praise. This time, it wasn’t. His most hard-core supporters did not take it well." 

Then, there's actual economist Michael Roberts' evaluation of crypto entitled Crypto corruption and un-Stablecoins.

Excerpts:  

“Bitcoin is a speculation and not an investment. Not regulated, not backed by any asset, only worth what someone is willing to pay.” — Matthew Stephenson

“It’s totally absolutely crazy, stupid gambling” — the late Charlie Munger, speaking in 2023.

“Cryptocurrencies are highly volatile and therefore not really useful stores of value and not backed by anything,… It’s more a speculative asset that’s essentially a substitute for gold rather than for the dollar. ” Federal Reserve Bank chair, Jay Powell

“Bitcoin, it just seems like a scam…. I don’t like it because it’s another currency competing against the dollar.” Donald Trump, June 2021.

"It’s crypto week in the US. And the price of the leading cryptocurrency, Bitcoin, has hit a record $120,000 as the US Congress prepares to consider bills aimed at creating clearer regulatory frameworks for digital assets. In the next five days, US lawmakers will consider the Genius Act, the Digital Asset Market Clarity Act, and the Anti-CBDC Surveillance State Act. The aim is to make “America the crypto capital of the world”....

"From the start, cryptocurrency craze has been riddled with fraud, criminality and corruption – the cases of which are too numerous to mention all. In an annual report last September, the FBI revealed that fraud related to crypto businesses soared in 2023 with Americans suffering $5.6bn in losses, a 45% jump from the previous year. Sam Bankman-Fried, who founded the now bankrupt FTX crypto exchange, was sentenced to 25 years in prison in March 2024 by a New York judge for milking customers out of $8bn. Last month, the US Securities and Exchange Commission charged Unicorn, an investment platform that promised cryptocurrencies backed by real estate, with a $100mn fraud that misled more than 5,000 investors.

"The dream of the techno enthusiasts that cryptocurrencies would replace state-issued currencies like the dollar or the euro and so free individuals from the ‘heavy hand of state regulation’ in a new free world of money has never materialised. Instead, what has happened is that the mega financial institutions have taken over control of these currencies and are turning them into what they hope will be a highly profitable set of financial assets to suck in investors."

 

 

Friday, July 11, 2025

A (belated) Look at Finding the Money [The MMT Film]

July 10, 2025

Steven D. Grumbine

My friend Maren Poitras’ Finding the Money does the vital work of dragging Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) out of academic journals and into the public square; but like a union rep forced to negotiate at a table built by bosses, the film’s framework bends under the weight of capital’s myths. Stephanie Kelton rightly hammers that “currency issuers can never run out of money” (Kelton 2020) while the documentary pulls its punches where it hurts most: exposing how the ruling class weaponizes deficit hysteria to strangle working-class futures. The blame for this shouldn’t be laid at Poitras’s feet; it’s an unfortunate element of many MMT stories.

The film brilliantly shows dunces like Treasury officials wringing their hands over “funding” Social Security, as if the government is some broke diner owner counting pennies rather than the creator of the dollar itself. This is where Finding the Money needs Clara Mattei’s razor-sharp class analysis: when she writes that “austerity is not economic necessity but class war” (Mattei 2022), she’s naming the game. That’s the peanut butter to MMT’s chocolate! The documentary lets politicians and bankers off the hook by framing monetary ignorance as mere confusion rather than what it really is: a systemic con job to make workers believe schools and hospitals are “unaffordable” while Pentagon budgets bloat like a corpse in summer. This secondary confusion myth is a recurring hyper-courteous MMTism that sometimes diminishes its own walloping wake-up call.

Where the film truly shines is its demolition of household budget analogies – those capitalist fairy tales that pretend the US Treasury operates like a family choosing between groceries bills and rent. Kelton’s explanation of money creation is the sledgehammer this lie deserves. But when it comes to showing who benefits from these myths, Finding the Money treats monetary policy like a faulty appliance needing repair rather than a butcher’s knife held to labor’s throat. It also leaves the viewer with the notion that all private sector savings are the same rather than the class war that can be truly exposed through an analysis of stratification.

To add context, consider what’s missing: the footage of Wall Street bankers high-fiving over interest rate hikes that jack up their bond yields while crushing indebted workers. The montage of CEOs blaming “inflation” for price-gouging as they report record profits (Weber 2023). The truth Mattei exposed – that economic “rules” are just class weapons dressed up in math – gets lost in the film’s focus on educating elites rather than arming the working class.

The documentary’s biggest blind spot? It doesn’t follow the money all the way to the picket lines. It doesn’t show the folks without teeth skipping dental care because of austerity. The student debtors losing their homes. The broken families. Auto workers striking for wage hikes, CNBC screaming about inflation. When tenants demand rent control, landlords howl about “market fundamentals.” Every time workers fight for more, capital shrieks “we can’t afford it” while amassing profit they didn’t earn but extracted. How much more powerful would the film be if it connected these dots?

This isn’t just about understanding money. It’s about seizing it. The film could’ve shown Puerto Rican workers building solar grids after privatized power failed them (Rapin, 2023) or Jackson, Mississippi’s solidarity economies (Cooperation Jackson, 2019) – proof that when we stop begging and start building, the “money” magically appears. We get plenty of talking heads but not enough torch-bearing workers marching on central banks which work for, and at the legal behest of, a completely captured Congress.

Finding the Money is a good first step, like a union organizer’s introductory pamphlet. But unless it names capitalism boldly and without reservation as the counterfeiter of artificial scarcity, unless it shows workers how to wrestle the decision making and money-creation power from the suits who’ve captured congress and hoarded it like dragons on a pile of gold, it’s only telling half the story. The other half? That’s written in the streets. But the streets need the information in this wonderful but inadequate documentary. Everyone needs to see this film; then start investigating class.

Watch Finding the Money for free on YouTube.

It is also available to rent or buy at findingmoneyfilm.com

References:  
Kelton, S. (2020), The Deficit Myth  
Mattei, C. (2022), The Capital Order  
Weber, I. (2023), Taking Aim at Sellers Inflation

Katherine Rapin (2023), The Grassroots Movement That Built Puerto Rico’s First Community Owned Microgrid
Cooperation Jackson (2019) The Just Transition, Economic Democracy, and the Green New Deal
Austerity, Class War, Inflation
Economic Justice, Film Review, Op Ed

Randall Wray on Modern Money Theory: Heuristics versus Paradigm Shift?

(from here)

This is a slightly revised version of the purposely provocative keynote presented at the FDR library for the Levy Institute Summer Seminar on Money, Finance, and Public Policy. References have been added. The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research, it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2025 All rights reserved ISSN 1547-366X 

Heuristics versus Paradigm Shift? 

Mainstream economics is in disarray. As Frank Hahn remarked four decades ago, “The most serious challenge that the existence of money poses to the theorist is this: the best developed model of the economy cannot find room for it.” He was speaking of General Equilibrium theory, but his claim applies equally well to Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium theory, which is used by all the major central bankers of the world to model the economy. 

Let that sink in. Our central bankers use a model to understand the economy that has no money, no banks, and no financial system. The Queen of England asked why none of the mainstreamers foresaw the Global Financial Crisis. Their failure was baked into their model. 

Remarkably, even insiders at the Fed recognize the dismal failure of orthodoxy. Jeremy Rudd began a recent Fed research paper, claiming, “[n]obody thinks clearly, no matter what they pretend […] that’s why people hang on so tight to their beliefs and opinions; because compared to the haphazard way they’re arrived at, even the goofiest opinion seems wonderfully clear, sane, and self-evident” (Rudd 2021). 

He goes on to list ideas that “‘everyone knows’ to be true but that are actually arrant nonsense”—including all the main ideas of orthodox theory. They are all nonsense. All accepted as dogma. 

To paraphrase what Keynes said a century ago, mainstream theory’s application is not only limited to a special case (i.e., an economy that does not use money), but is also dangerous when applied to the “facts of experience” to formulate policy. The evidence is plain to see all around us: in an era of multiple pandemics that threaten the continued existence of human life on planet Earth, we are stymied by imaginary constraints concocted by economists. 

Over the past 30 years, Modern Money Theory (MMT) got much of it right. Its proponents foresaw the fatal flaws of the euro. They predicted the oncoming global financial crisis and warned that the policy response would be insufficient, so the recovery would take much longer than necessary. And when the COVID-19 pandemic hit, they offered a policy response—targeted spending to address problems without setting off inflation. 

In that last crisis, at least some policymakers listened to MMT. Former Congressman John Yarmuth (D-KY), Chair of the House Budget Committee, had embraced MMT and helped to usher through trillions of dollars of pandemic relief without worrying about “pay-fors.” As he correctly argued (as quoted in Wray 2021), “Historically, what we’ve always done is said, ‘What can we afford to do?’ And that’s not the right question. The right question is, ‘What do the American people need us to do?’ […] Once you answered that, then you say, ‘How do you resource that need?’” 

He went on to argue that, as the US government issues its own currency, finance is never the problem. What matters is resource availability. 

As MMT predicted, trillions of dollars of deficits did not cause interest rates to spike, or the dollar to crash, or attacks by bond vigilantes, and did not force the US government to default. 

All the finance was keystroked, all the treasury’s checks cleared, all the bonds were taken-up, and the dollar remained strong. The deepest recession on record was reversed with the fastest recovery. MMT was in the news, again, but this time occasionally with a positive spin. The pandemic response was claimed to be the first real world experiment that applied MMT. 

However, the pandemic lingered on longer than most expected—with continued supply chain disruptions, new viral outbreaks, organized political resistance to science, and price-gouging by mega-corps with pricing power. 

Inflation rose. MMT was blamed. In truth, the policies were not what we advocated—spending was not well-targeted, jobs were not created directly, capacity was not enhanced. 

As Yarmuth warned, all eyes need to be focused on resources, not on finance. 

A chief architect of the neoliberal world order, Larry Summers, announced with fury that he was offended that the “newspaper of record” would devote space to MMT: “I am sorry to see the nytimes taking MMT seriously as an intellectual movement. It is the equivalent of publicizing fad diets, quack cancer cures or creationist theories.”[1] 

Jason Furman—a favorite of Democratic administrations—fumed: “I don't think MMT makes any sense. I also don't think it's played a role in shifting us on deficits.”[2] 

And now, of course, we are back to the deficits—two of them (trade and government budget), both chronic, both seemingly intractable problems. As I have explained, [3] the two are inextricably linked, although not in the way that conventional analysis claims. 

I do think they have become a problem and I think MMT needs to clearly address them. Too often MMT proponents have responded to critics with simple heuristics—a list of talking points that are meant to represent descriptions of reality—freed of theory or policy recommendations. 

While heuristics are useful in introducing MMT to beginners, they cannot substitute for careful economic analysis. We might have relied on them excessively. Let me give some examples of problematic heuristics: 

  • Taxes drive money 
  • Government spends currency first, then taxes it back 
  • Imports are a benefit, exports are a cost 
  • Bond sales are just a reserve drain 
  • Government sets the price level 
  • Floating exchange rates maximize domestic policy space 
  • There’s no financial crisis so great that fiscal policy cannot resolve it 

While there’s a kernel of truth in each, all are historically, theoretically, and practically problematic. Each follows logically from carefully constructed assumptions. None strictly applies to the economy we actually live in. 

It is often said that MMT is mainly a description of the way things work—and that theory and policy can be added as desired. I’ve even said (Wray 2024a) that MMT is for Austrians, too! 

I want to walk that back. Description without theory is not possible. Theory without a paradigm is not possible. We need a paradigm to formulate theory, and a theory to formulate description. Once we have got all that, only then we can tackle policy. 

Both the University of Missouri—Kansas City and the Levy Institute have played a big role in the development of MMT and share a paradigm that has shaped our approach. I’ll briefly outline the building blocks: 

  • From Marx, Keynes, Veblen, Minsky: Marx’s M-C-M’; Keynes’s Monetary Theory of Production; and Veblen’s Theory of Business Enterprise. 
  • From the Institutionalists (Veblen and Minsky): money is all bound up with power: to do good and bad; Money is the most important institution in Capitalist Economy 
  • From the (Post) Keynesians (Keynes, Davidson, and Minsky): money and uncertainty; Money and contracts; Holding money “quells the disquietude” (as Keynes put it); Endogenous money 
  • From the Chartalists (Knapp, Innes, Goodhart, and Minsky): state money and currency sovereignty 
  • From Functional Finance (Lerner and Minsky): state money and the approach to fiscal and monetary policies 
  • And, finally, the Sectoral Balances approach (Godley and Minsky): focus on balance sheets and macro balances; balances do balance! 

TOGETHER: that is MODERN MONEY THEORY 

As Minsky used to say, a general theory is useless. While Keynes called his revolutionary book The General Theory, Minsky argued it to be a misnomer—it is a theory of the capitalist economy where money plays a special role. 

James K. Galbraith has argued that Keynes purposefully borrowed his title from Einstein as he was trying to do for economics what Einstein had done for physics. 

But economies are far more complicated than the physical world. Many heterodox economists argue that biology is a better analogy because the living world is always evolving—from a past that we can sort of understand to an unknowable future. That better captures what Keynes was doing—a Darwinian Revolution. 

As Minsky insisted (Wray 2017), capitalism evolves—there are 57 varieties—and our theory must continually evolve along with the facts of experience. Money is at least 5,000 years old, as David Graeber (2012) claimed, and its role changed significantly over those thousands of years. For most of economic life, money didn’t matter much—until modern capitalism was incubated by the New World’s slavery on the backs of captured Africans. 

All the modern institutions we associate with capitalism came out of slavery—modern finance, administration, accounting, labor discipline, policing, and warfare, as well as the peculiar form taken by American democracy (Wray 2025a). 

Thus, our theory needs to be institution-specific. Our paradigm is monetary production: unlike in all previous economic systems, the purpose of production—from the perspective of those in control—is to start with money to end up with more money. Satisfaction of needs is not the goal of those who control capital. 

We need a countervailing power—to use Galbraithian (1956) terminology—to ensure that needs are met, which can include government, labor unions, and social service organizations. 

Government in capitalist economies has always served two masters—the capitalists and the rest of us. 

Left to its own devices, capitalism is highly unsustainable—economically, socially, environmentally, and politically. Unlike tribal society—which could sustain itself for thousands, maybe millions of years—capitalism would self-destruct within a generation if it were abandoned to the invisible hand. 

That is what we saw, with depression after depression, once every generation until Roosevelt’s reforms and the creation of Big Government with what Minsky called Managerial Welfare State Capitalism and what Galbraith called the New Industrial State. 

In its modern guise—which we can date to 1870 (what Robert Gordon uses as the date for the beginning of the “special century”)—capitalism has gone through four or five stages according to Minsky. This final stage, Money Manager Capitalism, has run its course. We stand at the edge of a cliff, with no bottom in sight. 

Trump wants us to jump off. 

Let me return to the heuristics to explain why I believe they present obstacles to further advances in MMT. I am only going to tackle a handful of them here—but I think that many others also need to be critically assessed. 

Taxes Drive Money. We have often used the metaphor of the colonist who imposes a tax in his own currency and enforces payment with his gun. There are certainly historical examples, in Africa for example. 

And we often use the American colonies—that would pass two bills, one imposing a new tax and the other authorizing the issue of paper currency. All this is true. But money already existed— this cannot be an origins story and doesn’t shed the proper light on its nature. 

Money has existed for 5,000 years at least. As best as we can determine from historical evidence, it was invented as a unit of account to measure debts, for internal record keeping in the temples of Babylonia (Hudson 2018). This was before evidence of taxes or markets. 

What difference does this make? The first draws attention to illegitimate force—the evil colonizer. More importantly, it emphasizes money as something that exchanges hands: government spends a currency that then can be used to pay taxes, make purchases in markets, or hoard for later use. 

The second emphasizes record keeping, credits and debits. Modern governments do not spend physical currency, and taxpayers use only trivial amounts. Most of it is outside the US—used for illegal activity. Young people today have never bought anything except by flashing their smart phone. 

And the US government never spends currency, at least in America. Washington spends cash when they invade a country and want to pay mercenaries or bribe officials. 

I used to make fun of a prominent Post Keynesian who objected to MMT before a roomful of legal historians, saying: “I never think of taxes when I accept a US dollar—I accept dollars because I want to buy ice cream.” We all laughed at the superficial critique of MMT’s claim that taxes drive money. 

But the complaint resonates with 99 percent of the population—who never think of taxes as driving their demand for money. They want ice cream. And they don’t use currency to buy it. 

We need to move away from thinking about money as something that goes from hand to hand. The better metaphor is the baseball scoreboard, with banks replacing the Babylonian temple as the score keepers. Money isn’t something that you have or do not have. It is all about keeping track of debits and credits. And, as Minsky said, anyone can create money—the problem is to get it accepted. The question is whether the scorekeeper will give you a credit. 

As Minsky said, banks are not money lenders. They make payments for their customers. The “money” is created when they make the payment. Banks follow rules to determine whether they will make a payment for you. And they tally up what you owe—just as the Devil tallies your sins to determine whether he takes your soul. 

The central bank is the scorekeeper for the scorekeepers, and also for the government. It also follows rules that determine when and how it will make payments for banks and the treasury. Money is not something of which the government, the central bank, banks, or you can run out. As Mat Forstater says, the dollar is like the inch (or centimeter)—we cannot run out. 

I want to address three additional areas where I think overly simplistic logic leads down the wrong path—at least when it comes to developing an understanding of the way our form of capitalism works. First, there is the claim that as monopoly supplier of the currency, government can set any and all prices. The logic follows from the taxes-drive-money assumption. By imposing an obligation on you, government determines what you must give up to get the currency to pay your tax. As I have argued (Wray 2024b), this sounds a lot like the labor theory of value: if it takes an hour to earn a dollar, then the dollar is worth an hour of labor. 

This is the main idea behind the buffer stock approach to the job guarantee: government can maintain a buffer stock of workers paying a base wage to prevent the wage from falling and “selling” labor to private employers at a markup over that. 

By analogy, government can do the same for every other thing bought and sold. 

Well, what would that look like in the real world? A real mess. People joke about the Soviet Union’s attempt to regulate market prices but this would be that on steroids. 

It is completely inconsistent with capitalism. And as I have tried to make clear (Wray 2024b), the basic wage—the wage for ordinary labor— will not map directly to price. Capitalism operates according to a logic that generally tries to equalize rates of profit and exploitation—not according to the whims of a government that wants to set all prices. 

The second claim—that we can always counter a financial crisis by ramping up fiscal policy is wrong for the kind of financialized economy we had both in the gilded age before the Great Depression (often called Finance Capitalism) and since the unraveling of the New Deal institutions—beginning in the 1970s. This Money Manager Capitalism stage, with everything financialized is—to use the metaphor again—finance on steroids. 

 The Fed spent and lent $29 trillion dollars to save global finance (Felkerson 2011). The next financial crisis might take even more. 

You could say: well, just let the whole darned financial system fail. The real economy will still be here. That’s what we did in the Great Depression. As Minsky used to say: yes, the economy might recover, but by way of hell first. 

To be clear, I don’t support the way the Fed responded—it was a mess, much of it was illegal, and none of Wall Street’s criminal class was prosecuted. The money managers came roaring back and rebooted the bubblicious economy. 

But merely ramping up a fiscal response, alone, wouldn’t have saved our pension funds, our investments in our houses, or our university endowments. Even excluding all the fancy derivatives and other crazy financial products that total up to the hundreds of trillions of dollars, we have financial assets that are at least five times greater than the so-called real economy. 

We have to keep in mind that, in capitalism, the financial is more real than the real. This is a system based on producing money value, not one directed at satisfying needs. 

I’d like to change that—but we need to approach it sensibly, not by bringing on another Great Depression. 

Finally, there’s the MMT dismissal of the twin deficits problem. Since government cannot run out of money, budget deficits aren’t a problem—we might as well run them up. With a floating currency, trade deficits are a sign that we are winning: we get the stuff, they only get dollars. 

Trump says we are losing; MMT says we win. 

Minsky’s writings during the Reagan years showed great concern about both deficits. This has led some MMT proponents to argue that Minsky cannot be a guiding light for MMT. I have discussed Minsky’s views on this in two Levy publications (Wray 2018; 2025b). Let me quickly summarize his points. 

Creation of a large and chronic trade deficit means—by the sectoral balances identity—that we will have a large and chronic budget deficit. 

Minsky was worried that rival currencies could substitute for the dollar, so its value could fall— potentially irreversibly—forcing the Fed to keep interest rates high, while also putting inflation pressure on the US. The combination could lead to secular stagnation. 

What we saw, however, is that our two rivals—Germany and Japan—both dropped out of the running. 

Germany committed suicide by joining the euro and embracing austerity; Japan’s private sector ran out of steam and stopped investing, in part because the government also embraced austerity in an attempt to balance the budget. 

In the meantime, the US lost its industrial advantage (first to Germany and then to Asia). This was only partially due to trade—it had more to do with financialization of the economy—but contributed to inequality, the weakening of labor unions, and the rise of neoliberalism. 

We did get the secular stagnation that Minsky warned of, only relieved by serial bubbles—as Michael Hudson (2014) said, we became a Bubbles-R-Us economy. Propped up by serial bailouts by the Fed and growing budget deficits. 

For two decades, the Fed kept rates low, fueling the bubbles, but since COVID, the Fed has kept them high. And that means—as Minsky warned—that more and more of government’s spending is inefficient—going to interest and transfer payments, with much of the spending going abroad. 

The joke is that Uncle Sam is now just an army with a welfare system attached to it. Contrast all the recent presidents with FDR: his government made America great. His accomplishments are still all around us. 

Reagan successfully convinced us that government is a problem, not a solution—and the Democrats have largely reinforced that belief by doing little to nothing to help the working class (Tcherneva and Wray 2025). 

And, yet, the DOGE tech boys could not find any waste because we have created the most efficient way to run an inefficient system. 

As I said earlier, Minsky worried about secular stagnation. We temporarily staved that off during the Clinton years and for some time after by boosting finance—to the benefit of the FIRE sector (finance, insurance, and real estate) and what Citigroup (Kapur, Macleod, and Singh 2005) called the new Plutonomy—those billionaires who have taken over the government and the economy. 

A handful of counties around the US boomed while most of the country got left behind and turned red—as Pavlina Tcherneva and I have shown (2025)—even as Trump and Musk try to turn the country into a banana republic, with Trump’s favorability rating somewhere around 40 percent, the approval rating of the Democrats is stuck at 27 percent. 

A major exception to the stagnation was Silicon Valley: over the past two decades, tech is the sector that boomed alongside Wall Street. Interestingly, some of the early tech firms were involved in the payments system. That has come full circle with the second coming of Trump. This is, I think, the true aim of DOGE—to merge the financial and tech sectors, to financialize our data. 

We no longer live in a world of production of commodities by means of commodities[4]— including, most importantly, labor power. Capitalism is still driven by the quest for “more money” but the main source is not production of commodities. The labor theory of value doesn’t strictly apply: monetary wealth has been freed from production. Neither income nor profit flows are important for our plutocrats—as investigations by ProPublica (Eisinger, Ernsthausen, and Kiel 2021) have shown. Billionaires like Musk pay no income taxes because they have no income. 

Data is now the most important commodity in the world and DOGE has apparently developed the capacity to merge all the data collected by the government (including the IRS), banks, social media, and the insurance sector—especially health managers that deny your claims and startups that have your DNA and all other health records—into a one-stop shopping mall for sale to the highest bidders (Randles 2025; Chayka 2025). 

DOGE got hold of the payments system and can push the red stop button on any payment. They tested it on New York City—they actually shut down payments that Congress approved to help with the costs created by the clown governor of Texas who bussed immigrants and dumped them on the city (Tankus 2025). 

The Trump administration has paid over $100 million to Palantir (Frenkel and Krolik 2025) to consolidate all the government’s data on individuals, presumably to make it easier to go after the millions of Americans who could be added to an enemies list. To use the metaphor one more time: this could be Nixon’s enemies list on steroids. 

Am I paranoid? It is a strange new world. Capitalism is a system based on exploitation. While Marx focused on exploitation of labor, capitalism also exploits the environment, the family, the “others” outside its system. But the proponents of tech foresee a near-future in which labor is no longer needed as AI increasingly takes over all tasks. 

They don’t need your labor, they need your data, and maybe your eyeballs. 

AI’s most important task now is to accumulate all the data in existence. What then? It will know everything we know; it will be able to do everything we can do. And MMT teaches that it will be able to afford to do so. 

Maybe we should keep that a secret? 

But I don’t want to end on that note. Let me conclude. 

Conventional macroeconomic theory—of both the orthodox and (unfortunately) of much of the heterodox variety—takes an excessively “high in the sky” view. Unemployment is caused by too little spending. Inflation is caused by too much. Keeping taxes aligned—more or less—with government spending ensures it will not be inflationary. The solution to inflation is to cut spending or raise taxes. 

MMT is dangerous because it lets the cat out of the bag: taxes do not finance government spending. This gives politicians a license to run up spending that will cause inflation. Best to keep the wool pulled over the eyes and insist on tax “pay-fors,” or let the DOGE boys stop the payments. 

MMT’s view is different. The composition of both taxes and spending matters, and so there are two reasons that trying to match them is misguided: (1) government doesn’t need the revenue, and (2) there is no reason to believe that matching them means government’s impact approaches neutral. 

Spending on unemployed resources puts them to work with little inflationary consequence. Spending on a fixed price-floating quantity basis reduces further the inflationary danger. (That is what the Job Guarantee does.) 

Spending to increase productive capacity also reduces the danger of inflation, and can raise the danger of deflation. Clearly, no tax hikes are required in that case—we might need tax cuts if productive capacity grows to exceed what can be supported by spending. 

A good example is healthcare: Medicare for All would cut spending in half—from over 18 percent of GDP to perhaps 9 percent, the amount typically spent by other rich countries (Wray and Nersisyan 2020). We would need a big tax cut to offset the disinflationary impact. 

Likewise, it matters what kind of tax is imposed. A financial transactions tax, or a billionaire wealth tax, or a tax surcharge on millionaires is unlikely to take a significant amount of demand out of the economy—no matter how much revenue they raise—so are not likely to reduce inflation (Wray and Nersisyan 2020). 

Forget billionaire taxes to raise revenue. Instead, tax billionaires to destroy their wealth—impose a 120 percent wealth tax to take all of it, and send them a bill for the rest. Incentivize them to try to work their way out of the debt. 

On the other hand, a broad-based income or consumption tax will reduce demand significantly. Other methods can also be used if desired: rationing, patriotic saving, or postponed consumption. 

All this is important to support a transformative Green New Deal—or any other large scale government initiative. As Yarmuth insisted, we need to identify the resources needed and then release them from current use as necessary. 

We can use taxes for that purpose, although we might need to include other methods—such as banning oil drilling and fracking, or conscripting resources—to obtain the resources needed for the public purpose. 

We then spend to put those resources to use. If we have matched resources to purposes well, then there will be no significant inflationary pressures no matter the budgetary outcome. 

This sort of analysis must be undertaken, but it scares both orthodox and heterodox economists accustomed to relegating decision-making to the “invisible hand” of the market. 

Yes, planning will be required. Yes, it is difficult. Yes, mistakes will be made. But there is no alternative. 

A half-century of neoliberalism has brought the world to the brink of collapse. Only concerted effort and cooperation by the world’s governments provides any chance of survival. Understanding MMT does not make this easy. But it helps us to recognize what the true constraints are: resources, initiative, politics, imagination. And whatever it is that AI plans to do with us. 

_____________________________________________ 

Footnotes: 

1 https://twitter.com/LHSummers/status/1490424193611141121. Accessed 5 November 2022. 

2 Jason Furman: https://twitter.com/jasonfurman/status/1083394281547722752 . The New York Times article also stated, “’M.M.T. was already pretty marginal,’ said Jason Furman, a Harvard economist, noting that, in his view, most policymakers and prominent academics ignored it already.” (Accessed 5 November 2022.) 

3 https://www.levyinstitute.org/publications/ratings-agencies-downgrade-the-dollars-exorbitant-privilege/ 

4 As Saffra put it. 

_____________________________________________ 

 

REFERENCES 

 Chayka, K. 2025. “Techno-Fascism Comes to America.” The New Yorker, February 26, 2025. https://www.newyorker.com/culture/infinite-scroll/techno-fascism-comes-to-americaelon-musk. 

Eisinger, J., J. Ernsthausen, and P. Kiel. 2021. “The Secret IRS Files: Trove of Never-BeforeSeen Records Reveal How the Wealthiest Avoid Income Tax.” ProPublica, June 8, 2021. https://www.propublica.org/article/the-secret-irs-files-trove-of-never-before-seenrecords-reveal-how-the-wealthiest-avoid-income-tax. 

Felkerson, J. A. 2011. “$29,000,000,000,000: A Detailed Look at the Fed’s Bailout by Funding Facility and Recipient”, Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Series, No. 698. https://www.levyinstitute.org/publications/29000000000000-a-detailed-look-at-the-fedsbailout-by-funding-facility-and-recipient/. 

Frenkel, S. and A. Krolik. 2025. “Trump Taps Palantir to Compile Data on Americans.” The New York Times, May 30, 2025. https://www.nytimes.com/2025/05/30/technology/trump-palantir-data-americans.html 

Galbraith, J. K. 1956. American Capitalism: The Concept of Countervailing Power. Houghton Mifflin. 

Graeber, D. 2012. Debt: The First 5000 Years. Melville House: New York. 

Hudson, M. 2014. The Bubble and Beyond. Islet-Verlag: Dresden. 

Hudson, M. 2018. “Palatial Credit: Origins of Money and Interest.” On Finance, Real Estate, and the Powers of Neoliberalism, published April 6, 2018. https://michaelhudson.com/2018/04/palatial-credit-origins-of-money-and-interest/. 

Kapur, A., N. Macleod, and N. Singh. 2005. “Equity Strategy: Plutonomy: Buying Luxury, Explaining Global Imbalance.” Citigroup, Industry Note. https://delong.typepad.com/plutonomy-1.pdf. 

Randles, J. 2025. “23andMe’s Bankruptcy Puts 15 Million Users’ DNA Info on Auction Block.” Bloomberg, March 24, 2025. https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2025-03- 24/23andme-s-bankruptcy-puts-15-million-users-dna-info-on-auction-block. 

Rudd, J. B. 2021. “Why Do We Think That Inflation Expectations Matter for Inflation? (And Should We?)” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2021-062. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. https://doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2021.062 

Tankus, N. 2025. “Can Trump Arbitrarily Take Money From Anyone’s Bank Account?” The Rolling Stone, March 13, 2025. https://www.rollingstone.com/politics/politicsfeatures/trump-musk-doge-treasury-take-money-bank-account-1235295232/. 

Tcherneva, P. R. and L. R. Wray. 2025. “’That “Vision Thing’: Formulating a Winning Policy Agenda.” Levy Economics Institute, Public Policy Brief No. 158. https://www.levyinstitute.org/publications/that-vision-thing-formulating-a-winningpolicy-agenda/. 

Wray, L. R. 2017. Why Minsky Matters: An Introduction to the Work of a Maverick Economist. Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ. http://press.princeton.edu/titles/10575.html Wray, L. R. 2018. “Functional Finance: A Comparison of the Evolution of the Positions of Hyman Minsky and Abba Lerner.” Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Series, No. 900. https://www.levyinstitute.org/publications/functional-finance-a-comparison-of-theevolution-of-the-positions-of-hyman-minsky-and-abba-lerner/. 

Wray, L. R. 2021. “What Is MMT’s State of Play in Washington?” E-Pamphlets, August 2021, Levy Economics Institute, https://www.levyinstitute.org/pubs/e_pamphlet_2.pdf 

Wray, L. R. 2024a. Modern Money Theory: a primer on macroeconomics for sovereign monetary systems, 3rd edition, Palgrave Macmillan. https://link.springer.com/book/10.1007/978-3-031-47884-0 

Wray, L. R. 2024b. “The Value of Money: A Survey of Heterodox Approaches.” Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Series, No. 1062. https://www.levyinstitute.org/publications/the-value-of-money/. 

Wray, L. R. 2025a. Understanding Modern Money Theory: Money and Credit in Capitalist Economies. Edward Elgar Publishing: Cheltenham, UK. Wray, L. R. 2025b. “Ratings Agencies Downgrade the Dollar’s Exorbitant Privilege.” Levy Economics Institute, Policy Note 2025. https://www.levyinstitute.org/publications/ratings-agencies-downgrade-the-dollarsexorbitant-privilege/. 

Wray, L. R. and Y. Nersisyan. 2020. “Can We Afford the Green New Deal?” Levy Economics Institute Public Policy Brief No. 148. https://www.levyinstitute.org/publications/can-weafford-the-green-new-deal/.  

Is Deregulation the Solution to Homelessness?

Hoisted from the Davis Vanguard's comments on an article touting deregulation as a solution to the US housing shortage (edited for clarity):

Your conclusion that regulation is the culprit for a housing shortage is at least less-than-complete. First, from the Wharton Index you cite: “Markets around the national average (WRLURI2018 index values within one-tenth of a standard deviation from zero) include Houston, TX, Columbus, OH, San Antonio, TX, and Pittsburgh, PA” Note that Houston is “average.” 

Just a reminder: Houston has no zoning at all. None! Yet it’s “average”! If zoning and regulation were the big factors responsible for a housing shortfall, how did it only achieve “average”? Why isn’t it the top of the list? 

As for whether zoning is dumb…of course! Houston has absolutely none and yet looks almost identical to Sacramento (both are inland ports, and have allowed auto-centric sprawl to dominate the landscape). One interesting note (to me): your illustration is a New Urbanist low-density neighborhood. The streets are a grid, the sidewalks are set back, and the curb radius at the corners is small and pedestrian-friendly. That’s not sprawl. Sprawl has spaghetti streets that twist and turn, disorienting the inhabitants (and terminating otherwise unpleasant views), sidewalks that put pedestrians in peril as they walk next to traffic, and massive curb radii that make pedestrian crossings at corners even more perilous. Thank goodness California has adopted “complete streets” for all new development…although Newsom turned down retrofitting the sprawl with better pedestrian amenities. 

Meanwhile, you ignore something that powerfully influences the current housing “shortage.” (Quotes because there are still more vacant homes than the US homeless population.) After the New Deal, the federal government built affordable housing until Nixon put a stop to it. Then, the Reagan administration cut HUD’s affordable housing budget 75% as it reduced taxes on the wealthy by roughly half, and with Bush 41, raised payroll taxes eightfold. After the New Deal, there was no significant homeless population until the ’80s. Surely that deserves a mention! 

Sprawl is “conspicuous consumption” of land, eliminating the “missing middle” (medium densities) of housing that might make land costs less onerous in housing, and imposing perhaps the most regressive tax possible. It requires all driving age inhabitants to own an automobile. We desperately need pedestrian-friendly mixed-use neighborhoods that allow people to conduct their business without auto commuting. Nevertheless, we’re building sprawl after sprawl after sprawl. 

Incidentally, if you want to cut per-unit costs in half, just build duplexes rather than single-family homes. Of course that would mean providing services (parks, security, public health) and we can’t have that! De-funding the public realm is the current agenda. 

One other nice way to influence what’s built: Change FNMA/FHLMC property standards for new development. You may believe (with Frank Lloyd Wright) that “form follows function,” but in today’s economy, it’s really “form follows finance.” We’d stop building sprawl in five minutes if those loan underwriting standards changed to support something other than sprawl–really a racist “white flight” invention. 

Finally, you omit mentioning the land speculation that’s at the root of many of our current problems. Land speculation is an “industry” in California’s Central Valley, and the foundation of several large fortunes. It’s one reason land is expensive. We’ve got to pay those speculators! 

One example: North Natomas was once vacant farmland, and was 20′ under water floodplain surrounded by weak levees. It was deemed so unsuitable for development that a federal grant to increase regional sewer capacity specified a $6 million penalty if that capacity served North Natomas. 

The speculators weren’t bothered; they went to then-vice-president George H.W. Bush and got the $6 million penalty pay-as-you-develop rather than a prohibitive up-front fee. At the same time, they got $43 million in levee improvement grants to bring the weak levees up to pre-Katrina standards. Long story short, they sold land they optioned at $2,000/acre to builders, once they got Sacramento City’s approval, for as much as $200K/acre. That profit margin is called the “unearned increment,” and it’s 10,000%, gross(!) The current occupants of that neighborhood are now on the hook for all the post-Katrina levee improvements, but what matters is our land speculators have walked away with an enormous payday. 

Naturally, the speculators exchanged out of the sale to income-producing real estate, so they deferred even income tax indefinitely. 

In contrast, in Germany, the developers have to sell the outlying land they propose to develop to the local government at the agricultural land price, then purchase it back from that government at the buildable-land price. All that unearned increment inures to the benefit of the public, not lining some speculator’s pocket. And Germans have nice infrastructure, free college tuition and the arts budget for the city of Berlin exceeds the National Endowment for the Arts for the USA. 

Incidentally, there’s a reason Sacramento’s main public library has no free meeting room as most other public libraries do. Instead it has the “Tsakopoulos Galleria.” Why? Because we gave all the money to Mr. Tsakopoulos. 

Omitting these things and relentlessly celebrating the rollback of development regulation, as indefensibly stupid as it often is, just makes the Vanguard one more public voice calling for less intelligence in building our so-called civilization. (“Western civilization would be a nice idea” – Gandhi)

--Adam Eran

Today's Bee letter: Utilities

Responding to Sacramento Bee 7/17/25 p.20 Editorial writer Tom Philp wrings his hands over a Chamber of Commerce study that says solar incen...