ECOS Meets Financing
by Mark Dempsey (speaking for myself, not on behalf of Citizen’s Climate Lobby)
The
February meeting of the ECOS’ Transportation, Air Quality, and Climate
Change (TAQCC) committee heard a presentation from Jeff Spenser of the
Sacramento Transportation Authority (STA). He described why the recently
proposed Measure B to fund transit and roads was unsuccessful. He
explained the misconceptions of the public, and said that those backing
the losing Measure appear ready to try again, unfortunately, without
much interest in public outreach...again. Spenser repeatedly suggested
people contact their City Council person or Supervisor if they wanted to
have some input about what was proposed for funding in the next ballot
measure.
One
of the meeting’s attendees said Spenser’s suggestion to contact their
local representatives was answered when she actually did that by a local
representative who suggested that the attendee contact STA directly. So
the STA representative says to contact City Council and City Council
says to contact STA. Sort of “ask your father...ask your mother” writ
large. Nice, eh? The message, deciphered by another attendee: They
aren’t all that interested in your input.
It
may be the very definition of insanity to repeat what didn’t work
before, but that’s what it looks like is going to happen with “Son of
Measure B.” On the plus side, Spenser was eager to offer charrettes
about transportation funding as part of the process. I suggested some
similar procedures (facilitators, and/or what amounts to a grand jury
getting educated and making recommendations about such projects).
In
my experience, simply soliciting public input is much less sensible
than charrettes, facilitated discussion or pseudo-grand juries, and
since a lot of public comment is uninformed, and frankly nutty. In one
planning meeting I heard from a Carmichael woman who wanted
transportation planners to build a subway from somewhere near her house
to somewhere near her work. This would work if the fare were $100,000 a
trip, but not otherwise. Just FYI, such heavy rail projects are
typically ten times more expensive than light rail, which is roughly ten
times more costly than bus rapid transit. You need the densities of the
Bay Area to make heavy rail really viable. Carmichael doesn’t qualify.
...which
prompts a question to ask about one frequently mentioned transit
project: Why not tenth-as-expensive bus to the airport instead of the
proposed light rail? (One possibility: the whole region’s transit would
have to support early and late airport arrivals...not cheap!) But we must study it! Also: Is light rail a stalking horse for more floodplain development in North Natomas? Who knows?
Not
much else was discussed at the TAQCC meeting, but in the midst of what
followed the STA presentation, John Deeter asked for suggestions about
alternative ways to finance transit, besides a (regressive) sales tax
increase. I spoke up. What follows clarifies and expands on what I said.
The Planning-and-Paying-for-it Problem
First,
what we’re really discussing here is how to do intelligent planning
based on real costs and consequences. Despite the bad name it gets
(“only Commies believe in central planning!”), a modern economy needs
planning. There’s a widespread sentiment that the “invisible hand” of
the market automatically takes care of any needed forethought, but that
is just not true. Now, primarily private banks and the military are
doing planning, and with results that suit their agenda(s). Could
auto-intensive sprawl also feed the same banks who finance auto dealers?
And is that pope fellow still Catholic?
Unfortunately, the word “primarily” is really an understatement, not an exaggeration. See here
for a description of the designed-to-fail local land-use planning that
solicits public input, and its abominable treatment of public sentiment
(it’s an old editorial. but it still applies). One Australian planner
says “You Yanks don’t consult the wisdom of democracy; you enable mobs.”
Unfortunately, that’s all too true.
Speaking
as a person who was in the real estate business for years and spent
several of those years on a County Planning Advisory Council, I say we
could discard the region’s entire land use “planning” apparatus without
harming anything. Houston Texas did just that, and between regulations
imposing street standards and minimum lot sizes, has produced a city
virtually indistinguishable from Sacramento in every significant
respect. Houston has no
planning department at all. So...the market plans! … Just kidding. Even
Houston requires regulations for streets and lot sizes, and
constructive planning for sustainable outcomes requires more than that.
Read the above-linked editorial for details.
I’m
not the only one who feels modern land-use planning is useless. Jane
Jacobs says “The pseudoscience of [land-use] planning seems almost
neurotic in its determination to imitate empiric failure and ignore
empiric success....to put it bluntly, [sprawl planners] are all in the
same stage of elaborately learned superstition as medical science was
early in the [19th] century, when physicians put their faith in
bloodletting.” (from The Life and Death of the Great American City)
Meanwhile,
with many admirable efforts from its members, ECOS has soldiered on for
the decades since I’ve been contributing to the organization and
attending meetings. Has local planning improved, or has ECOS called it
out as “elaborately learned superstition”? No. Is the default work
product of our local planning process mostly ecologically sustainable,
transit-friendly development? No; it's far and away mostly sprawl.
So
ECOS has been pushing this stone up the hill, and it’s rolled back down
to the bottom every time it reaches the top with a few small victories
along the way, but no game-changing transformation for several decades
worth of effort. The biggest new thing in local planning is that, like CalTrans, the locals have decided to adopt “Complete Street” standards--something ECOS may have endorsed, but did not initiate.
I
talked to ECOS’ former executive director, Graham Brownstein, about
this and he reminded me that ECOS has performed a valuable service,
sending letters of protest to various local agencies, even ones who
don’t welcome public input. Those letters are the basis of successful
CEQA lawsuits, and with such suits, ECOS has stopped some truly awful
development, so I don’t want to discount the work and effort of ECOS and
its members. On the contrary, I’m grateful that ECOS persisted in this
thankless task, but would like it to do even better.
Meanwhile,
I suggested to Graham that planning-by-lawsuit is problematic at best.
Not only that, the process for the unprosecuted bad development hasn’t
changed significantly. The default “planning” process still diffuses
public protests, produces profits for land speculation and builds more
sprawl...and not much else. Even now, with 20 years worth of vacant
infill land undeveloped in the region, land speculators are proposing
even more outlying, greenfield development (the opposite of infill) to
extend North Natomas development northward, and to develop the land
south of 50 near Folsom (where there’s no water, but who cares? It’s
profitable!). It’s not sustainable!
So
how about trying something different? It may just be a different stone
on a different hill, but what ECOS has been doing amounts to settling
for small victories in a process that needs to change dramatically. (And
Darrell Steinberg’s SB 375 and expiring entitlements are
nothingburgers, too.)
If
the current process were not bad enough, even when developers actually
build the Transit-Oriented Development essential to improve air quality
and climate, banks can sabotage the result. Phil Angiledes' Laguna West
was designed and approved according to Peter Calthorpe’s Transit
Oriented Development (TOD) standards. Unfortunately, viable transit and
pedestrian-accessible mixed-use shops require enough riders and shoppers
within a walk of them. When builders were building out Laguna West,
rather than build the designed densities, the banks would not offer
apartment / condo financing...so now Laguna West is a slightly more
pedestrian-friendly version of sprawl with lower than designed density,
and less-than viable neighborhood commerce and transit. Remember, in
architecture, it's not Frank Lloyd Wright’s dictum: "Form follows
function," it's "Form follows finance."
The Public Banking Solution
Since,
ultimately, banks dictate what gets built, what would happen if banks
actually served the public interest rather than the profit of sprawl
merchants, a favored few land speculators, auto dealers and other
plutocrats? Something better, perhaps…?
Public
banks have been around in the U.S. for a long time. FDR used the
Reconstruction Finance Corporation to fund the first Bay Bridge and the
Tennessee Valley Authority. Incidentally, Eisenhower ended the RFC, so
the second Bay Bridge was underwritten by private lending from Goldman
Sachs.
Unfortunately,
most of us are unfamiliar with how banks actually work, and completely
clueless when it comes to public banking and the creation of currency.
For the big picture, read “Let’s Stop Pretending We’re Insolvent.”
Also,
just to reassure you, the ideas expressed in that editorial and the
following come not from my fevered imagination, but from a school of
economics called “Modern Money Theory” (MMT). It includes some of the
few economists who actually predicted the Great Recess, and is
respectable enough that Senator Bernie Sanders hired MMT economist
Stephanie Kelton to be an advisor to the minority on the Senate budget
committee. (Here’s a 35-page MMT document if you want a more comprehensive look at it.)
The
TAQCC meeting’s discussion following Spenser’s presentation centered
around strategies to better fund transit, and guide the kinds of land
use that supports it. Transit is squarely in TAQCC’s wheelhouse, but
somehow discussions about the funding options are not (or so says John
Deeter, to me).
That’s
odd since profit (i.e. money) motivates most of the ecologically
damaging land speculation and unsustainable development in the region.
On top of that, nearly half of the cost of large public projects like
purchasing electric buses is the financing. In my not-so-humble opinion,
ignoring funding options costs ECOS insights, credibility and a
potential avenue to get its way.
We’re
all familiar with the excuse for third-rate transit, or really any
below par asset in the public realm: “Hey, we can’t pay for [whatever it
is]! We’re out of dollars!” And people tend to accept such excuses
because they’re familiar with the experience of being in a household
that has to tighten its belt. However, there’s a fundamental difference
between currency creators (government, banks) and currency users
(households) that makes such thinking really counter-factual.
I’ll
add that the ultimate shared good in the public realm is what we call
“the environment.” If only private interests can finance public
improvements, then private profit, not public good, is what sets the
agenda, and dictates what’s build. With (risk-averse) profit seeking in
the driver’s seat, we’ll continue to get pretty much what we’ve got now.
Following the dictates of profit, rather than sustainability, also
exacerbates the already enormous current inequality in income and asset distribution in the U.S.A.
As a consequence, the plutocrats get to command a disproportionate amount of the economy’s products (because they’ve got
the money). And because too much money is not ever enough, they also
tend to lobby to privatize public goods (roads, schools, etc.) and even
arrange for the public realm to be under-funded so they can clamor for
even more privatizing and financializing such public assets (sell off
the parks, drill for oil on federal land, etc.) so they can profit even
more. One example: Federal funding for higher education has declined 55%
since 1972. Ever wonder why tuition keeps rising, and student loans
grow ever larger?
The
destination for this trend is a population full of debt peons, and an
environment that is really just a series of rent-extracting toll booths.
This is where austerity leads. A tiny sliver of the population desires
that destination, too.
State
and local governments are typically currency users, as opposed to the
fiscally unconstrained currency creators at the federal level. However,
even state and local governments can create currency too, if they have a
bank. For a more in-depth discussion of public banking, I recommend
Ellen Brown’s book The Public Bank Solution: From Austerity to Prosperity. For something shorter try her “How to Cut the Cost of Infrastructure in Half”... or just keep reading what follows.
How the Banks do it: Fractional Reserve Lending
Most
people believe banks lend the money on deposit, but that’s not true.
Banks practice “fractional reserve lending,” a custom that began with
medieval goldsmiths. Since the goldsmiths had the safes, they would
store people’s gold, issuing receipts for what they had on deposit. For
convenience, depositors would use the receipts as money. It didn’t take
too long before clever goldsmiths discovered they could make loans, and
issue more receipts than they had gold. That practice still persists
today as fractional reserve lending.
Today,
banks use dollar deposits from the public, or reserves borrowed from
each other or borrowed from the U.S. central bank (The Federal Reserve,
or “The Fed”) instead of gold, but the principle is the same: like those
medieval goldsmiths, banks create the money they lend without touching
what they have on deposit. One current estimate of the proportion of
money created by banks: 97% of the money supply.
The
good news is that many modern nations also have something the
goldsmiths didn’t have: deposit insurance that promises to repay
depositors if everyone demands their deposits back all at once. When
that occurs, it's called a “run on the bank”--an unfortunate side effect
of fractional reserve lending. Beyond deposit insurance, if a bank is
“too big to fail,” the Fed will simply create more money to bail it out.
According to the Fed’s own audit, it pushed $16 - $29 trillion out the
door in the few months after Lehman Brothers filed bankruptcy.
Modern
banks create money by creating checking accounts for the loans they
make (“loans create deposits” is the saying). They type an account
balance in a computer to do that.
So...if
a someone borrows to buy a house, the bank’s bookkeeping makes sure the
amount in the borrower’s checking account (which is the bank’s
liability) exactly equals the amount of the borrower’s mortgage (which
is the bank’s asset). That balance is required by another medieval
invention: double-entry bookkeeping. Notice that reserves do not appear
at any point in that transaction.
If
the house seller deposits the proceeds of sale in the same bank, then
reserves don’t appear in that transaction, either. The bank debits the
mortgagee’s checking account and credits the seller’s account, moving
and balancing electronic entries in their “scorekeeping” software.
When
buyer and seller patronize different banks, the Fed steps in to settle
the score between total accounts in those different banks and ensures
both banks have “adequate” reserves. If a bank doesn’t have adequate
reserves it can always
borrow from the Fed in unlimited amounts. The current Fed Funds Rate is
0.75% (per year!). That’s the bank’s borrowing cost. Among other
things, what this means is that in the unlikely event that a public bank
had to borrow all the
money it lent, it could still make a quarter percent gross profit by
charging as little as one percent per annum for the loan.
As
I’ve said before, public banking is not a novelty; other nations use it
extensively, but the financial sector in the U.S. does not want
competition, so you will seldom hear it mentioned, and even the
“liberal” Jerry Brown vetoed funding to study how to create a California
state bank. As I said in the ECOS meeting, such a state bank (like they
have in North Dakota) would eliminate the need for Brown’s
multi-billion-dollar "prudent reserves" for California’s budgetary
emergencies; it could offer the state a line of credit secured by future
tax collections. Currently, those "prudent reserves" come out of the
budgets for schools, the indigent and the elderly. All of that is
unnecessary.
So...I
wouldn’t suggest the process of getting public financing for the
transit or land-use infrastructure ECOS wants would be easy.
Nevertheless, until the public controls money creation, money will
continue to be our master not our servant, and we’ll continue to get
second-rate infrastructure with the excuse that we’re out of dollars, in
a way that inures to the profit of the plutocrats…. Something roughly
like settling for some bizarre outcome in a sporting event because the
scorekeeper supposedly ran out of points. If that sounds crazy, well,
that’s because it is crazy.
Just
as vultures want animals to die, for some small portion of the
population, the austerity of “we’re out of dollars” is a desired
outcome. Those are the opponents of what I’d describe here, AKA “vulture
capitalists.”
Incidentally,
one other common popular narrative says government spending in the U.S.
is “big.” But the U.S. has a large country and large economy. Look at
Wikipedia’s ranking of government spending
as a percentage of GDP, and you’ll see the U.S. ranks 46th in the
world, between Argentina and Luxembourg. Subtract 11% of that U.S.
spending to make its military spending something realistic for an
average first world nation (and still more than double what China spends
on its military), and U.S. government spending ranks between Bhutan and
Namibia. (Notice that you can sort the columns in that Wikipedia
article by clicking on the headers in the comparison table.)
No
wonder our infrastructure is starting to look like we live in a third
world country! Think of how Flint Michigan is starting to resemble
Namibia. That “big government” meme is another lie that serves the
vulture plutocrats.
Some Potential Projects
Public
banking could fund many potential projects promoting sustainability
that are not currently possible with private financing’s requirements.
Public financing would both enable innovation, and be cheaper too. After
all, half of these projects’ costs are typically financing costs.
So...reducing the financing cost of RT’s proposed purchase of electric
buses would be in line with ECOS’ mission.
Another
example: Public banks could finance projects to make suburbs more
transit-friendly. Suburban shopping centers seldom include housing.
Private banks won’t lend to make a second or third story of apartments
on top of Safeway. If a public bank funded such developments, the
private sector would likely imitate their success, too. Oddly enough,
we’re also short of affordable housing.
Are “lifestyle centers” (shopping centers that include housing) successful, and even profitable? From Wikipedia:
“Lifestyle centers typically require less land and may generate higher
revenue margins, generating close to 500 dollars per square foot,
compared to an average of 330 dollars per square foot for a traditional
mall.” Mogavero Notestine even has a proposal to make Sunrise Mall into a
Citrus Heights town center by integrating housing into this shopping
center. Note: Counting on the private sector to innovate like this is at
least a long-odds bet. (See this TED talk for the details.)
Incidentally, a California Infrastructure Bank
does exist, it just can’t fund much. The Bay Bridge revamp was too big
for its underwriting standards (so Goldman Sachs underwrote that
project). I’ve talked to the bank’s director about another potential
public bank project: providing housing for the homeless. The region
spends an estimated $40 million basically on police and emergency room
costs related to the homeless (says Jeff Harris). Talk to any homeless
advocate and they’ll say we could save 50% - 80% of those costs by
simply housing homeless people, providing them with transitional
counseling (called “Housing First”). Salt Lake and other cities have
already done this with such savings, so the concept is not just
theoretical.
Unfortunately
the costs of Housing First are front-loaded, arriving before the
savings, but such situations are why loans were invented. A loan would
help even out the expenses, saving more than double what funded the
quarter-billion-dollar Kings’ stadium subsidy (again: underwritten by
Goldman Sachs).
However,
according to the California Infrastructure Bank’s director, financing
money-saving homeless projects remains taboo for their underwriting. He
complained that they can’t even fund solar panel projects based on
utility savings; they need to see revenue before they’ll lend.
I’d
suggest that the Infrastructure bank’s board who configures their
underwriting standards are unclear on the concept of public banking, or
are sabotaging its potential to serve the privatizing plutocrats rather
than the public.
FYI,
solar panels cost roughly half what they did even five years ago, and
yield an estimated 17% return on investment for residential
installations, according to SMUD’s calculations...but that’s not enough
to persuade the infrastructure bank’s board to change its underwriting
standards.
Conclusion
Public
banking offers an alternative method of financing both transportation
and land-use improvements. … and yet this solution is not one I’ve
never heard about from ECOS, any other environmental group. Despite the
dismal record of public institutions and their indifference to public
input, such an alternative might even be successful too, but we’ll never
know if no one brings it up.
In
my humble opinion, unless the public starts to grasp the levers of
power implicit in such money creation, the current oligarchy that runs
public policy in the region will continue to plead “We’d love to do
[whatever it is], but we’re out of money….” In other words "There is no
alternative to austerity." As I’ve demonstrated above, that's an excuse
which simply doesn’t hold water.
No comments:
Post a Comment
One of the objects if this blog is to elevate civil discourse. Please do your part by presenting arguments rather than attacks or unfounded accusations.